|
Unit
3: The Case for Protection
Part
3: The Theory of Protectionism: Tariffs and Quotas
Protection essentially takes one of three forms: tariffs,
quotas, and non-tariff barriers. Tariffs are taxes levied
on a commodity crossing an international border. Quotas
are restrictions on the number of a certain good that can
be imported. Non-tariff barriers include all kinds of subsidies
and regulatory protection that doesn’t count as either
a tariff or a quota.
The basic motive for using tariffs is twofold: to protect
domestic industry from import competition and to generate
revenues for the government. For developing nations—such
as China—tariffs afford developing “infant”
industries the protection they need to mature. Moreover,
tariffs are an important source of revenue for such countries—as
they were for the United States until the early part of
the 20th century—since, even if developing countries
have income taxes in place (and can collect them), incomes
are frequently not high enough to sustain government operations
necessary for increasing economic growth. While tariffs
are more likely to be about revenue and fostering newly
developed industries in the developing world, for developed
nations the argument for their use rests squarely on jobs.
The effects within a given industry of a tariff include
higher prices, more domestic production, fewer imports,
tax revenue, and market inefficiencies because of the increase
in higher cost domestic production and loss of consumer
purchases caused by the higher market price. For example,
consider the following economic market analysis:
VIDEO: The Revenue and Protective Effects
of Tariffs
|
When tariffs are levied against foreign
imports, domestic production and prices rise, imports
decline, and the government increases tax revenue. |
In the absence of any trade with the rest of the world,
this market would be in equilibrium where the supply of
the product produced by US firms equals the demand for the
product by US consumers – at a price of 10 and a quantity
of 22. According to economic theory, this would be an efficient
outcome because at $10 there are 22 buyers paying less than
they are willing to pay (based on their demand curve) and
22 sellers being paid more than they are willing to accept
(based on their supply curve). In other words, each of these
22 market transactions is transferring a product from someone
who places a lower value on the product (the seller) to
someone who places a higher value on the product (the buyer).
And this is the fundamental argument in favor of market
systems.
Now, let’s consider what would happen in this market
if the rest of the world, which could profitably sell this
product for $5, were permitted into the US. Facing competition,
domestic producers would be forced to lower their price
to $5, making them only willing to sell 10 units and causing
job losses. On the other hand, at a price of $5, there are
34 buyers who would willingly pay at least that, so they
buy the 10 units domestic producers are willing to make
and import the remaining 24. Theoretically, this outcome
is more efficient than a market without trade for two reasons:
First, at a lower price, there are more market transactions—which
are beneficial to consumers—and second, the higher
cost domestic production, which would have only been produced
and sold at prices above $5 (units 10–22) are now
replaced by lower cost—more efficiently produced—imports.
Indeed, free trade by almost any empirical account, is more
efficient than no trade, and on average benefits consumers
more that it harms producers. But the distribution of trade
effects are very skewed: millions of consumers pay lower
prices—and this adds up to a lot—but some workers
lose their jobs. So while it is reasonable to favor trade
on the grounds that the gains are bigger than the costs,
neither can one ignore the devastating impact it has on
an unfortunate few.
Now let’s suppose that lobbying efforts by the workers
and the domestic industry that is hurt from free trade are
successful, and the government imposes a $3 per unit tariff
on the import competition. In order to recover the cost
of the paying the tariff, the rest of the world is forced
to raise their price to $8 ($5 free trade price + $3 tariff
= $8). This higher price has two main effects:
-
domestic
firms benefit because at a price of $8 they will be able
to profitably increase production to 16 units (which will
require the employment of more workers)
-
domestic
consumers lose because the price they pay goes up by $3
and the number of market transactions falls from 34 to
28 (which means that 6 consumers who would have benefited
from buying the product at the free trade price are now
left out)
Additionally, the government
collects $36 in revenue from the tariff since each consumer
is paying $3 more for each of the 12 units imported (28
demanded – 16 domestically supplied = 12 units imported).
In the end analysis, whether protectionism is good or bad
for you is really a matter of where you stand, realizing,
of course, that on average the total costs to consumers
almost always outweighs the total benefits to the workers
and industry being protected.
VIDEO: Supply
and Demand Analysis of Protectionism
And finally, outside of the industry receiving protectionism,
tariffs have other, secondary effects which must also be
considered. For example, fewer imports means fewer dollars
in the hands of foreigners that can be used to buy home
country exports. Tariffs on imports (such as steel or parts
assemblies for cars, etc.) increase domestic production
costs. In general, they also raise the cost of living, and
they have a dampening effect on foreign GDP—which
will tamp down their demand for goods of all kinds, including
exports from the home country. For example, it is estimated
that the steel tariffs mentioned above cost far more Americans
their jobs in industries which relied on steel as an import
than steel workers jobs were saved.
VIDEO: Non-industry Effects of Protectionism
clip 1
VIDEO: Non-industry Effects of Protectionism
clip 2
It’s important to keep in mind the general context
in which the debate about tariffs takes place. The claim
that imports cost jobs looks self-evidently true on the
face of it, and so looks like a good case for tariffs. However,
empirical evidence clearly suggests that relatively few
jobs in the US economy as a whole are lost due to import
competition. In a recent speech, Ben Bernanke, a member
of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, quoted
an estimate that suggested that about 2% of total American
job loss per year was due to trade. Moreover, tariffs often
temporarily put off a day of reckoning that an inefficient
industry ought to have faced long ago. Concern for displaced
workers, in other words, need not lead to advocacy of tariffs.
WEBLINK: Ben
Bernanke
Quotas
As mentioned above, quotas are limits on the quantity of
a good that can be imported into a given country. In a static
sense, quotas and tariffs have similar effects, except that
tariffs provide tax revenue while quotas put more money
per unit in the pocket of the foreign manufacturer. Both
raise price, lower imports, help domestic producers at the
expense of consumers, and cause market inefficiencies. Dynamically,
however, quotas can be even more protectionist than tariffs—explaining
why domestic industry favors them and the WTO rejects them.
For example, if domestic demand goes up when a quota is
in place, then the production gap has to be made up by domestic
producers, which means even higher prices for consumers
(and more profits for domestic producers). On the other
hand, if a tariff is in place, then extra production can
be provided through additional imports, which usually means
that price goes up less quickly than with a quota in place.
VIDEO: Quotas
Versus Tariffs
|
All files © Copyright 2010 UNCG DCL
Please report any problems or errors to the Site
Admin
Our Privacy Policy
|
|
|