Unit 3: The Case for
Protection
Global Trade Helps More
Than It Hurts
by Andrew Brod
Greensboro News & Record, August 31, 2003
Times are tough in the textile and furniture industries.
Foreign imports, most notably from China, are dominating
segments in both industries. It seems that every time one
opens the newspaper, another factory is being closed and
its jobs moved overseas.
Both industries are working hard to cope with the brave
new world of global competition. Some companies are going
with the flow, by contracting with foreign producers or
investing in foreign factories. It doesn’t help the
employment picture here as much as some would like, but
so far it’s helping those companies survive.
Other companies are fighting back and taking the foreign
competition head-on. They’re trying to improve their
processes, serve customers better, and focus on high quality
instead of low price. The companies that succeed in this
will emerge as strong and efficient global competitors themselves.
And there’s a third approach: Appealing to the U.S.
government to raise trade barriers against foreign-made
products. Such appeals make sense to many people who are
scared to death by competition from low-wage countries they
don’t understand. But trade protectionism is bad for
the American economy in the long run, and bad for a majority
of Americans even in the short run.
The textile and furniture industries are traveling nearly
parallel paths in their efforts to restrict trade, but the
textile industry is a bit further along. It has successfully
petitioned the federal government to consider imposing limits
on imports of Chinese products in three specific categories:
knit fabric, brassieres, and dressing gowns.
The basis of the appeal is the “China textile and
apparel safeguard,” a provision of the agreement that
allowed China to join the World Trade Organization in late
2001. Any WTO member that believes Chinese textile imports
are “threatening to impede the orderly development
of trade” may act to limit those imports. The U.S.
government has agreed to hear public comment on the petition,
after which it will make its decision, possibly late this
year.
For a claim to be valid under the China safeguard, the threat
of imports must be due to “market disruption,”
which would seem to indicate fast-changing economic conditions.
But the threat of low-wage foreign competition has been
a reality in the textile and apparel industry for many years
now. Can a process that’s been going on for so long
be thought of as a disruption, let alone a disorderly development
of trade?
The furniture industry has yet to make its appeal for trade
protection. But by October the industry intends to file
an anti-dumping petition that focuses on wood bedroom furniture
made in China. Dumping is defined to occur when foreign-made
products are sold here for less than in the producing country.
The conventional wisdom is that foreign producers are willing
to sell their products here below cost in hopes of driving
out domestic producers. Once they succeed, the foreign producers
are believed to be free to raise prices to exorbitant heights.
There are many problems with this folk theory. One big problem
is that there’s scant evidence that the above horror
story has ever happened. If it were a reality, we’d
have seen prices rise as our trade exposure increased. However,
precisely the opposite has happened. International trade
hasn’t raised American consumer prices, it’s
lowered them. Trade has been a significant factor in keeping
inflation in check for so long.
A second problem is that supporters of the anti-dumping
petition seem to want to have it both ways. They tell us
that it’s hard to compete with China due to its low
labor costs, but then they tell us that Chinese companies
are selling furniture in America below cost. Well, which
is it? Low prices due to cheap labor, or low prices due
to dumping?
Third, what some see as dumping is actually just an example
of a very common pricing practice. It’s called “price
discrimination,” and it’s not necessarily a
bad thing. If two markets can be separated from each other,
geographically or otherwise, there will generally be lower
prices for the same product in the market in which there
is more competition.
Airlines charge lower fares to vacation travelers than to
business travelers, because vacation travelers have more
options and that means airlines have to compete harder for
their business. For similar reasons, electric utilities
charge lower rates to residential users than to business
users. And when foreign producers export to countries in
which product competition is tougher than at home (which
is often the case in developing economies like China’s),
they often charge lower prices abroad.
Do vacation travelers and residential electricity users
mind having their purchases partly subsidized by businesses?
Of course not. But for some reason, we’re told that
we should mind if the product is furniture and the subsidy
is coming from overseas.
In any case, it’s hard to know who “they”
and “we” are. China’s total exports have
tripled since 1994, and according to the investment bank
Morgan Stanley, fully 65 percent of that dramatic growth
is due to subsidiaries of, and joint ventures with, multinational
firms. Many American furniture makers fall into this category,
including a number of the anti-dumping petitioners. Don’t
you just love irony?
Trade protectionists in both industries claim that they
support free trade and are merely fighting “unfair
trade” and ensuring a “level playing field.”
These are great sound bites, but it’s very hard to
determine who is and isn’t playing fair in the trade
game. And sometimes the cheaters aren’t whom you’d
expect.
It may be that China subsidizes the production of both textiles
and furniture, as the trade protectionists claim. But the
U.S. is hardly an innocent flower in this respect. For example,
we subsidize our farmers quite aggressively. Along with
France, we practically lead the world in this dubious category.
We may not be allies in the war in Iraq, but the Franco-American
alliance in farm subsidies has held firm, harming developing
countries around the world by flooding them with artificially
low-priced agricultural goods. If China is a kettle, then
we’re a pot.
Another of the “unfair trade” claims is that
China is a non-market economy. One textile-industry leader
even referred to it as a communist country. Such characterizations
are years out of date. China has been moving rapidly toward
a market economy since Deng Xiaoping started instituting
economic reforms in the 1980s. To be sure, the government
has retained its authoritarian grip on society, so it’s
certainly not a democracy. But neither is it a communist
country. Some markets in China are more hurly-burly and
competitive than in the U.S.
One measure of a market economy is the central government’s
share of national income. The bigger the share, the less
room there is for markets to allocate goods and services
freely. In socialist industrial economies like Sweden and
Israel, the national government can account for well over
a third of the economy (local governments add to that).
The average share among developing countries is lower, and
in China it’s lower still, around 11 percent. In the
U.S., it’s about 20 percent. The upshot is that it’s
more accurate to describe China as a developing economy
than as a non-market economy.
Yet another claim is that China manipulates its currency,
the yuan, to promote exports unfairly. It’s true that
the yuan’s value is fixed by the Chinese government,
and most analysts agree that it’s significantly undervalued.
China manages this by buying huge quantities of dollars
and dollar-dominated securities, thereby bidding up the
value of the dollar relative to the yuan. However, those
purchases also help finance the massive budget deficits
the Bush administration is racking up. Without China’s
cheap-yuan policy, the budget situation in Washington could
be much gloomier than it already is. Is that really what
we want?
The efforts by the textile and furniture industries to restrict
trade are understandable, but wrong-headed. They threaten
to undermine the traditional leadership of the United States
in promoting free trade around the world, and to harm American
consumers in the name of protecting a relatively small segment
of the economy.
It’s hard to see through the plant closings, but on
balance, international trade is a boon to the American economy.
According to the Office of the U.S. Trade Representative,
the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) and the
creation of the WTO have raised the annual income of the
average family of four by about $1,650. Multiplied across
the entire population, this represents a net benefit of
over $100 billion per year. And this is the opinion of a
Bush appointee regarding Clinton-era trade policies.
However, abandoning calls for protectionism doesn’t
imply abandoning industries and regions that are harmed
by international trade. Free trade doesn’t mean government
is free of responsibility for what happens in a market economy.
Trade benefits society as a whole, but it also changes some
lives and hurts some people, and in this case they’re
our friends and neighbors. The government needs to do what
it can to retrain and compensate them, and help us all prepare
for the future.
Here’s the biggest problem with the current push to
restrict trade: It won’t work. The global economy
is a complicated machine, and closing off one valve just
causes another to blow. We might as well try to outlaw gravity.
As an executive of a Chinese furniture company put it, “The
furniture industry will just go to other countries, like
Vietnam, Indonesia, or Malaysia. This is the trend of the
global marketplace.”
Copyright © 2003 News & Record