icampushelp  
head_image

course descriptonprofessorsyllabuscalendarunit1unit2part1part2part3part4part5part6part7part8weblinksreadingsassigmentsunit3unt4unit5unit6unit7unit8logo
Globalization > Unit 2 > Part 7

Unit 2: Why Trade?

Part 7:  Economies of Scale-Driven Trade

Economies of scale also drive trade specialization. An economy of scale occurs whenever “bigger is better” (or at least cheaper). That is to say, if a factory or an entire industry can lower the average cost of producing their products by producing more of them, then they are operating within an economy of scale.

In general, two kinds of economies of scale influence patterns of trade: internal economies of scale, which result from the quantity produced inside the factory; and external economies of scale, which result from the size of an entire industry located in a particular place.

Internal economies of scale. We will first explore the role of internal economies of scale on trade by considering, for example, two types of automobiles: SUVs and sports sedans. The factories that produce these automobiles have huge research-and-development and assembly-line design costs associated with producing each type of vehicle. Such factories exhibit great potential for internal economies of scale because larger production volumes of a given type of automobile will spread out these “fixed” costs, resulting in lower average costs per unit.

Now, let’s initially assume that the US and Germany have identical factors of production—land, labor, and capital—and that the two nations also have the same preference for SUVs and sports sedans. According to our analysis in the previous sections, and the fact that similar preferences would result in similar quantities of production, both the US and Germany should have the exact same production costs (and no potential to gain from trade).

But what would happen if the relative preference for SUVs and sport sedans were not the same? What if Americans like SUVs because of the US’s low speed limits and big parking lots, while Germans preferred the thrill (and safety) of driving sport sedans on their no-speed-limit autobahns? The German factory would make a few more sport sedans and a few less SUVs, while the opposite would happen in the US; this would make sports sedans cheaper to produce in Germany and SUVs cheaper to produce in the US because of the economies of scale being (or not being) realized.

To further exploit this cost saving, the US should just specialize in what the majority of American’s want (SUVs) and use the excess production of SUVs to trade for what the minority of Americans want (sport sedans). Doing this would reduce the development and assembly line set-up costs and allow the citizens of both nations to buy automobiles for less.

Diagram of internal economies of scale.


External Economies of Scale.
An external economy of scale is a cost advantage for an industry in a nation that can more or less materialize by chance, but nonetheless influences patterns of trade. For example, in the American mid-west, an external economy of scale resulted from the fact it just happened to be where Henry Ford’s first “assembly line” auto plant was built. Once built, other manufacturers, parts suppliers, laborers, transportation grids, and such, also sprang up there. This agglomeration of like-minded interests led to competition and cost savings, which allowed Ford and the other automobiles factories located there to produce cars at lower costs than anywhere else. So, sometimes the reason a country trades one thing instead of another is simply a matter of historical happenstance.

An early auto assembly line
Source:http://www.internet-encyclopedia.org/upload/9/97/AssemblyLine.jpeg


All files © Copyright 2010 UNCG DCL
Please report any problems or errors to the Site Admin
Our Privacy Policy

 
 
  foot