icampushelp  
head_image

course descriptonprofessorsyllabuscalendarunit1unit2unit3unt4unit5part1part2part3part4part5part6weblinksreadingsassigmentsunit6unit7unit8logo
Globalization > Unit 5 > Part 5
Unit 5: Exchange Rate Systems

Part 5: Dollarization, Currency Boards, and Single Currency Areas

Some countries have recently considered making another country’s currency their own: in particular, adopting the dollar. This is a highly consequential step for any country, one that has to be considered very carefully and, in our view, should not be done without consultation with United States authorities. On one hand, dollarization offers the attractive promise of enhancing stability. On the other hand, the country also must be prepared to accept the potentially significant consequences of doing without the capacity independently to adjust the exchange rate or the direction of domestic interest rates. The implications for the United States are also consequential. We do not have an a priori view as to our reaction to the concept of dollarization. We would also observe that there are a variety of possible ways for a country to dollarize. But it would not, in our judgment, be appropriate for United States authorities to extend the net of bank supervision, to provide access to the Federal Reserve discount window, or to adjust bank supervisory responsibilities or the procedures or orientation of U.S. monetary policy in light of another country’s decision to dollarize its monetary system.

~Treasury Secretary Robert E. Rubin, April 21, 1999

Source: http://www.internationalist.org/
billetes0102.jpg

Since the end of the modified Bretton Woods gold standard in the ’70s, the volatility of exchange rates and financial markets has increased markedly. In a way, that is to be expected: both the volume of trade and the size of foreign exchange markets have also increased rapidly, and the oversight of the postwar Bretton Woods system is gone. The increasing volatility has especially been a problem for late-industrializing economies—such as those in South East Asia—and developing economies all over the world. Without stable currencies and capital markets, industrialization, especially on the IMF’s terms (i.e. export-oriented growth), can be difficult, if not impossible.

Dollarization. One solution to currency instability has been “dollarization.” When a country dollarizes, they accept the US dollar (or some other nation’s currency) as their own currency; by doing so, they usually hope to contain inflation, which not only hampers consumer confidence, but also drives away foreign investors. Theoretically, the process of dollarization is quite simple. Suppose, for example, that Mexico dollarized. How would the process work? Well, if the current exchange rate is 10 pesos per dollar and there are 10 billion pesos in circulation, then Mexico could “destroy” their currency and ask the US Treasury to print them a billion US dollars. As a result, goods that used to cost 10 pesos in Mexico would now cost a dollar.

But how would adding a billion dollars into circulation affect US prices? It wouldn’t. Why? Because the billion newly circulating dollars are covering a billion dollars worth of Mexico’s output, which is now priced in dollars. In other words, the overall ratio of the US money supply to output covered by dollars remains the same, implying prices in the US will be unaffected. Does Mexico’s dollarization cost anything for the US? Other than the cost of the paper, ink and labor required to make the dollars for Mexico, not really.

What about the cost for Mexico? By using dollars, Mexico is effectively handing over control of their money supply—and their monetary policy—to the US Federal Reserve. Why would Mexico do this? If Mexico had a history of exchange rate volatility and mismanagement, it would be hard for them to attract foreign investment, so dollarizing eliminates this risk. In reality, of course, Mexico is not dollarized, although it hasn’t gone without consideration; but Panama and El Salvador are, and Argentina, Peru, and Uruguay each have more dollars than their own currencies on deposit in their financial systems—allowing them to successfully defend the value of their currencies against the dollar.

Currency board. Argentina’s efforts at dollarization suggest another related mechanism for curbing financial volatility: a currency board. A currency board oversees the domestic money supply and ensures financial stability by making sure that domestic currency is backed by another. In Argentina’s case, the supply of Argentine pesos had to be matched one-for-one with dollars on reserve. So, even though the Argentine peso was still the currency in circulation, it had dollarized by assuring investors and consumers that domestic money supply would not stray from the supply of reserve dollars on hand.

A currency board, then, is more of an official exchange window for a nation than a central bank—its sole purpose is to ensure that any domestic currency introduced is fully covered in reserves by the currency it is backed against. As such, any nation wishing to successfully guarantee and defend its currency in this way must also be willing to relinquish sovereignty and forgo debt-financed monetary expansion. Although Argentina was able to temporarily cure its hyperinflation problem this way, the need of the government to run deficits when the economy slowed pushed the peso off the dollar standard and led to Argentina’s sovereign debt default—and a severe political crisis—in 2002.

Source: www.bbc.co.uk/russian/specials/euro/index.htm


Single currency. Finally, we might consider a single currency area, such as the European Union, as a response to increasing financial volatility. This area is defined by separate national governments and economic institutions, but a monetary policy guided by a supra-national policy-making central bank. There are basically four reasons why countries would enter into a currency area agreement:


 

VIDEO: The Theory of Dollarization and Currency Boards

 

  • First, and most obviously, a single currency area eliminates the transactions costs of changing one currency into another: in doing so, it simplifies accounting and allows consumers to compare cross-national prices more easily.
  • Second, a currency area eliminates price volatility that is a function of exchange rates alone: this will generally ease business transactions and obviate the need for many kinds of speculative hedging.
  • Third, such an exchange area can cement trust among nations. At the very least, trade disputes that might come about because of fluctuations in the exchange rate will be eliminated.
  • Finally, for developing countries, a common shared currency can give them credibility in financial markets, which could lead to lower interest rates, easier credit, and greater opportunities for economic development.

 

 

 

 

 

All files © Copyright 2010 UNCG DCL
Please report any problems or errors to the Site Admin
Our Privacy Policy

 
 
foot