icampushelp  
head_image

course descriptonprofessorsyllabuscalendarunit1part1part2part3part4part5part6weblinksreadingsassigmentsunit2unit3unt4unit5unit6unit7unit8logo
Globalization > Unit 1 > Part 2

Unit 1: Historical and Contemporary Overview of Globalization

Part 2:  Between the World Wars

The period between the two world wars was punctuated by political and economic upheaval, the rise of Stalin and the Soviet Union, the Spanish Civil War, the emergence of European fascism, and the Great Depression. The US’s Smoot-Hawley tariffs of 1930 were emblematic of the changes in the world economy. European overproduction in the agricultural sector (an after-effect of agricultural build-up during the first world war) drove world grain and corn prices down, and thus drastically depressed the value of farm land in the US. The Smoot-Hawley tariffs drew up agricultural import restrictions and provoked other industries to seek relief from international competition. The US government complied. By 1933, the US had the highest levels of tariff protection it had ever had. These drew retaliatory measures from all of the US’s trading partners. In general, the world’s largest economies increasingly relied on “beggar-thy-neighbor” policies which, like Smoot-Hawley, benefited one country at the expense of others. World trade collapsed. During this period, U.S. imports from Europe declined from $1,334 million in 1929 to $390 million in 1932; U.S. exports to Europe fell from $2,341 million in 1929 to $784 million in 1932. World trade declined by roughly 66% between 1929 and 1934.

Between the wars, suspicion grew about how well the market could achieve just or efficient outcomes on its own. The market economist who enunciated skepticism most clearly was John Maynard Keynes, whose Treatise on Money was a flashpoint for debate. Although the Treatise is fairly technical, covering topics ranging from the theory of monetary fluctuations to the diffusion of price levels, its basic premises are pretty simple. Keynes argued, quite contrary to the traditional liberal, “free-market” view, that money was not neutral in economic transactions—it wasn’t simply a veil for the real value of goods being traded. This implied that prices did not always adjust immediately to supply or demand shocks so as to equilibrate the market at full employment—especially in an international context: since prices were “sticky,” we might expect there to be perhaps prolonged periods of unemployment of labor or capital. This view, rearticulated in The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, was widely accepted as the basis for national economic policy especially during and after the Great Depression, when the inability of the markets to clear at full employment was on glaringly on display in the US and the Europe.

 
***Tip Box: According to classical economic theory, when an economy falls out of full employment equilibrium due to an unexpected downturn in demand, as was the case with the 1929 stock market crash, for example, prices (wages) will quickly fall until demand (employment) is restored. This prevailing view of economic order was called into question by Keynes when the economy failed to recover from that crash. Keynes did not hold the classical view of an automatic recovery, believing that there were structural impediments in the system—such as labor unions—which would prevent such an adjustment from naturally occurring. Keynes believed an economy could get “stuck” in prolonged periods of unemployment and that only with the aid of government intervention would an economy return to full employment equilibrium.***
 


WEBLINK:
For more information on seminal economist John Maynard Keynes, log onto:
John Maynard Keynes
http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/bios/Keynes.html

Austrian economist Friedrich A. Hayek articulated the opposite view, arguing that prices were essentially signals about scarcity—money was an impartial and transparent vehicle for such information. In this view, boom-and-bust economic cycles were more or less unavoidable, and Keynesian-style monetary policy would only distort the essentially efficient adjustment process and make everyone worse off. Whatever the theoretical merits of this view, its policy implication in the Great Depression—do nothing; wait for the market to correct itself—was impossible politically. So Keynes won the day.

WEBSITE: A short bio of Friedrich A. Hayek can be found at:
Friedrich A. Hayek
http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/bios/Hayek.html

Keynesian wisdom became part of conventional economic thinking in industrialized capitalist countries for the next forty years. In a sense, Keynes saved capitalism from itself—that is, he saw that we didn’t live in the perfect world of liberal economic theory, and so posited a way of achieving second-best aims with imperfect markets. Although many associate Keynes’s name with big government per se, Keynesian theory was aimed at building realism into a theory of markets, not at a theory of market governance. On an international level, Keynes’ ideas translated into a skepticism about free trade, since the theory of free trade rested on some of the same fundamental principles as the theory of free markets and transparent money. Nonetheless, world merchandise exports grew at a healthy clip in the postwar period—at 7.1% per year on average between 1950 and 1970. While not the 11.1% of the thirty years that followed, this accomplishment was nothing to sneeze at.

 

All files © Copyright 2010 UNCG DCL
Please report any problems or errors to the Site Admin
Our Privacy Policy

 
 
  foot